Tyler, you mentioned Titpon's HU book at start of this video.. just curious if you have learned the majority of how Game Theory applies to poker through books? and if so, which books do you think offer the best information on this?
(I know the following authors have written books on GTO Poker: Will Tipton, Matt Janda, Bill Chen and Jared Ankenman, and Philip Newall.. have you read the books by all of these authors? and are there any other authors that you know of that have made a good contribution to this area? )
Hey Tyler, great video, very interesting stuff... it seems like the moral of the story is that we need to be careful in the assumptions we make about what hands are still in our opponents range on the river, because small mistakes there could lead to large overbetting mistakes...
That's a great summation! I was surprised at how much the betsizing oscillate on small equity differences. Adding an EV calculation into the excel spreadsheet would be of good value.
Great video. Are there ever any spots where the optimal bet sizing formula might give us a output that is a very large bet size, but our range won't be able to come up with enough bluffs to balance that bet size? In this case are we better off tailoring our bet size down to get the appropriate value:air ratio in or do we just choose the optimal bet size and add all of our air and villain's best response is to just fold 100% of his bluff catchers? It seems like in the latter case we give ourselves a nice free roll vs non-clairvoyant players.
Justification for the smaller betsize is that we could bet smaller with our nut hands, get called gain value, then bet bigger with our bluffs and get folds. So the right play here is for our opponent to fold to any betsize. From a practical standpoint, I'd just go all in, because it makes me seem more aggressive and can never be wrong and is unexploitable. AND its far bigger mistake for them to call the all-in bet with a 1-A strategy, then to call a small bet with 1-A strategy. Let them make big mistakes!
incredible video. In this example, is jamming despite the fact that we dont have sufficient bluffs better than just the size that balances our value to bluff ratio?
Yes, because if our opponent chooses to call, he now loses money (when we bet bigger than size that balances our values to bluff ratio). If we only balance he breaks even, so calling isn't a really a mistake.
so if we have a value hand that wants to bet 75% pot, but we only have enough bluffs to support a 50% pot bet, we should bet 75% of pot regardless? is this because either way, we win the whole pot (bc calling 50% bet has 0 EV and folding to the 75% bet has 0 ev)? so we freeroll that he by mistake might incorrectly call the 75% bet?
And is this the maximum EV for our whole range if its EV is the entire pot on the river? (bc if our EV cud get any higher, our opponent cud just better their expectation by folding their entire range?)
sorry for all the questions but wud really appreciate if u cud comment on this question above ^. Appreciate you taking the time to answer everyone and so promptly. Im just really thinking about this bet sizing strat and I think without adequate bluffs in my range, ive been sizing down for the reason to be 'balanced' when makes no sense to do so.
This is a cool graph. If you bet >= 50% pot in your example then your EV against optimal strategy is always = 1 pot. That optimal strategy is always fold at > 50% pot (and call or fold when bet = 50% pot). However if our opponent plays suboptimally calls any betsize sometime our EV > 1 pot at bet > 50% (and our EV keeps increasing as we bet bigger) and EV = 1 pot when bet = 50%. So we are really freerolling our opposition by betting 75% pot here. Either we win 1 pot against GTO or we win > 1 pot against Anti-GTO.
45o hand you lead A23r flop BTN v BB. I don't think I play a leading range on this texture from the BB as I just have a pretty sizable range disadvantage and only a slight nut advantage having all 45 combos where btn likely only has 45s. What's the idea behind that lead and why you do prefer a lead to x/ca or x/r?
I thought this opponent was tight enough to only have suited fours, whereas I felt I was playing K4o, Q4o, 64o and 54o in this spot. Given board texture, my range has a real advantage on the 5 and he checks close to 100% of the time in position. This makes betting very appealing (its also usually bet as a bluff because he will rarely call the turn and river here with AJ and that's close to the cutoff for a profitable bluff. ).
Its pretty incredible what small perturbations to the system can do :). Shows just how essential good hand reading is (and tricking your opponent into misreading your own hand).
Not exactly the topic of the video but a spot I'm interested in:
16:40 6cTh3dAd "the ace hits his range a lot harder than mine and slowplaying my traps here is really important"
I don't really believe in this (slowplaying the traps in this spot). This particular hand could be a good candidate to check call, but I wouldn't totally consider it a trap anyways, which I guess we see in the equity sim (and we will want to have some pretty good 2 street check calling hands here).
I prefer an overbet strategy with the nut hands (33,66, AT for sure) at a high frequency instead of a check raise. If he's stabbing or bet calling the turn too often, then we can start employing a higher c/r freq as an adjustment.
In theory I believe the overbet strategy should yield more EV than a check raise in a spot where we have significant nut combos and our opponent basically never has nut combos (traditional polar vs capped concepts etc). This could tie back into the topic of the video, where 33 has extremely high equity and we can overbet the turn and then overbet many rivers for a huge sizing as an optimal strategy.
Of course in the optimal solution there is probably some degree of mixed strategy where we do check percentages of those nut combos at equilibrium, but I don't think it has to be very often.
I like your logic and I'd like this post twice if I could!
I should qualify my thought with check a3 and a6 here to strengthen my range, but also be willing to overbet hands clearly over the top of his range (AT, 66, 33).
i agree with this analysis but a few things: 1. TT seems to be a very reasonable check back ( i do it a lot as a defense versus ur strat and the fact that standardly vbetting 3 streets wont work well with blocker effects) 2. AA can check at a certain frequency as well on flop.
So when we start blasting in overbets, we start to run into these combos on occasion when we have 33/66 (not so much with AT bc of blockers obv), but i doubt this is a huge concern.
I do agree though an overbet leading strategy can work well, and balance it with the lots of straight draws/FDs we will have without SD value that want to realize their equity.
We arent leading any other hands though right? I think an overbet lead or a check is best.
The EV of check raising don't come from the fact that he will not always cbetting his air hands on the flop and can delay bet them at a certain frequency turn as this card hits his range pretty well ? We can put pressure on his As x by check raising large and overbet river and include the appropriate ratio of bluffs. I wouldn't bet too too much because as you said he can have some traps (TT/AA sometimes), and if he knows our strategy it incentives him to check back a lot of other trap hands
If it goes check check we can always bet large on the river, not too large imo as he can easily check back his weakest As x turn and bluff catch river no ? I would probably bet pot or small overbet and include some bluffs.
I"m curious why Garrett and FBB both like over betting turn compared to x/r'ing. It looks like a turn where we're going to face a bet from a wider range than we're going to get a call from when we bet, so wouldn't our value region be gaining the most from check/raising? I would think Ax+air will make up more than Ax, Tx-3x but I could be miscounting there. I guess I should also add that we likely make more vs his Ax by taking the x/r line rather than over bet turn, bet river.
I've played around with the formula in the spreadsheet a bit, and one thing I noticed is that increasing stack size makes the optimal bet size decrease. Is this because villain's traps are assumed 100% equity and he can just shove vs our bet and add the appropriate number of bluffs to make us indifferent? Apologies in advance if the question is nonsensical as much of this material is over my head. Thanks for another great video.
Tyler, optimal bet sizing is definitely an interesting topic, but how reliable do you think what you found out is to the games you play which probably aren't this optimal with sizing. Does all what you've discovered by doing math make you want to bet closer to the optimal bet sizing or is that just something you did out of interest and curiosity?
The key issue is the small perturbations in the system causing large swings in betsizing, so the numbers themselves will never be terribly valuable. What is valuable is realizing that betting 1/3rd pot with a nut hand is or overbetting a "range merge" value hand is a big mistake the vast majority of the time. I think about this video as more of a lesson in how NOT to bet.
I enjoyed the video. For the most part, I feel like I understand the general principle of Tipton's formula but am having trouble reconciling it with betsizing strategies I've used or seen in the past.
In the video, you use the equity of your specific hand v opponent's range in the formula. However, in game, I assume you are not usually scaling your betsizes according to the equity of your specific hand. In practice, does it make sense use the [equity of our entire value range] to estimate a single bet size for our entire value and bluffing range?
I also wanted to point this out with a couple more thoughts to the question.
Since we can't valuebet every single hand with its optimal betsizing against a good opponent we group our value hands in different betting ranges.
Consider this example: we decide to have two betsizes in a river spot where a straight is possible. In the smaller betsizing we can have some 2pair and sets and a small % of straights + bluffs. In the bigger one we have only nut hands+bluffs. So when we bet for the smaller betsizing should we:
a) bet a size that is 100% accurate to the weakest hand we valuebet;
b) bet a size that is not optimal for any of our value hands but is somewhat inbetween.
If option b) is the right answer then it becomes really tough to calculate which betsize we should use for our range. In many spots if we do an in-between size we might risk of going over the valuebetting threshold for our weakest hand, resulting in a bad bet with our weakest value and lower than optimal with our better value hands that comprise that range. It seems to me there's room to possibly expand Tipton's formula to include these considerations to explore optimal range betsizing.
Interesting concept, really like the video!
But shouldnt we use range vs range equity instead of hand vs range equity for our calculations? I dont really understand how we could apply this line of logic for our bluffing sizes if we just use the equity for single hands.
Using one or two betsizes for entire ranges makes a lot of sense, but its more demonstrative to show a hand vs range situation. However, you can easily extend the logic to range betsizes.
great video.
If we do not have enough bluffs to balance our sizing, and our opponent is clairvoyant, should we go with a smaller sizing that he is indifferent to calling to?
You say above we learn that we should not bet small with our nut hands, but if that is the only way we can get called, than isn't that correct?
Thanks FBB, Go bigger, because we always win > pot. (If he correctly folds, we win pot). If he calls incorrectly, we win > pot.
And yes there is some strategy choice against a bad player, where going allin with bluffs and betting small with value bets is the best play. But I have rarely met this sort of player and if he starts foldign to small bets and calling big ones we now lose money in this situation. Seems like a big mistake to take a spot where we win > pot and turn into a -EV situation on the off chance our opponent meets some weak tight specifications.
Very helpful video. The video also portrays the limitations of the human mind when playing a live game. In theory, you’re exploitable if your choose a bet size that is far away from the optimal bet size. Understanding that the human mind can’t calculate this quick enough, is there a realistic strategy to minimize exploitability with regard to bet size? It was pretty eye opening how minor changes to equity could have such an effect on bet size. I guess something similar to Zach Freeman’s recent video (Building Realistic Strategies For Strong Ranges On Poor Flops) but in slightly different context…
Every movement toward GTO betsize will yield improvements in EV. I like to think about more as evolution rather than multiplication. In evolution, every animal slowly adapts better to its environment (moves close to GTO). But in multiplication 7 X 7 = 49 is always true and if I wrote 7 X 7 = 51 it would be wrong (Its either right or wrong).
Doesn't it make a difference in the last hand, that all the equity that he has comes from chops, and you're actually beat ~0% of the time (and thus cannot value cut yourself)?? Seems misleading that you would use the same numbers on the spreadsheet as if you were beat ~9% of the time. I don't think the EV would be much lower if you just shoved there, which is obv what you will be wanting to do with 64.
Though maybe it's optimal to shove 64 and air, and vbet 54 smaller.
Actually the equity number accounts for chops (it adds 50% equity hands into the range for all chops). We don't want to end up in situation where we are only called by 4x and 64s. Then our bet actually becomes negative -- chop with 4x and lose to 64s.
Im trying to reconcile 2 modes of thought when i reach these river spots. My current one is "ok, i have x amount of value bets, which allows me to have x amount of bluffs," and i then pick a sizing.
In this video you are offering another mode/layer of thought: "how much equity does this specific hand have against his range, and whats my optimal bet size given stacks?" My question is how you go about bringing these two together.
Its a good question, and ultimately the answer is that the average range equity wins out. If there is not enough bluffs in your hand range, you will take a hand with showdwon value and turn it into a bluff (at an optimal sizing for your hand range. (Hand equity was for example only). This means all your bluffs will be +EV and your showdown value hand will be equal EV between checking and betting. Its actually a super awesome spot to be in. :)
aren't your bluffs zero EV in a balanced range? if we dont have enough bluffs, we take worse hands in range (probably thats wins lets say 5% of time) and bluff them but how do they stay at +5% of pot in EV? It still loses to all their bluff catchers. So you expect ppl to slightly overfold to keep it at around +5% of pot EV?
Hi FBB,
If we bet twice pot and don't have enough bluffs in our range, then our opponent should always fold. Our bluffs are now worth more than zero. They are worth 1 pot. So we should always bet our bluffs, because checking them is worth zero EV and betting is +EV. If we continue with a large range with some showdown value hand, we should add bluffing with hands that have less than 1 pot EV in this example, because when our opponent folds we make 1 pot EV. Eventuallly our opponent will settle on a range that makes the strongest "bluff" (hand with showdown value) indifferent to calling. All bluffs lower than this will be positive. I'd encourage you to construct some ranges in a free version of piosolver and try this out. Seeing is believing.
"eventually our opponent will settle on a range that makes the strongest "bluff" indifferent to calling." Can you expand or elaborate this point? Im not sure I understand, and i feel its the crux of your point.
Otherwise we wouldn't bluff enough because our bluffing range of 0 EV bluffs ( betting are strongest bluff would be negative so we would check ti) this would be less than enough to make him indifferent to calling so he would always fold. Which means we would gain vaue against by bettig our strongest bluff. This oscillation is indicative of exploitative play.
oops my bad... after checking some numbers.. if there is money behind, villain raises his nuts along some bluffs denying our share of the pot making it inferior to x/back and showdown our hand.
My question is when we use this formula should we compare against villan's full range he gets to the river with or against the bluffcatching range? @18:25 with the A3 two pair hand you put Ax and KdQd, KdJd, with I don't think villain will bet/call turn and then call river, but in the other example with A5 3b pot you said he won't bluffcatch with hands like QJ and put only bluffcatching hands in his range, but this changes our equity drastically and as we saw that matters a LOT.
P.S.: Tyler is not only a really entertaining/smart person to learn from, but he makes great drinking-game videos as well. When you hear 'in this situation' just take a shot with your friends. :)
Thanks for the compliments! We should compare against his bluffing catching. In the first spot with A3 both KqQd and KdJd are bluffcatching hands. Most of my bluffs will be low flush draws/gutshots so those hands actually have decent equity against my range. In the A5 hand of course we have 87hh, JhTh, QhTh+ but those are only 4 combos, so QJ only has 10% against my range (which makes it an autofold).
There are a lot of questions in here about how the formula applies to playing our range, which I am interested in as well. Perhaps it could be helpful to think of this formula as a way to find the optimal bet size for each hand in a vacuum, prior to constructing our overall strategy.
As I understand it, this is a formula for bet sizing pre-equilibration. In our actual strategy, we will mix hands into different ranges to keep our opponent indifferent between his actions against each range.
For example, this formula shows us that our nut hands want to bet very big and our thinner value hands want to bet smaller based on their equity. But if we always bet big with the nuts and smaller with our thin VB's, then our opponent can attack our smaller bet size. So at equilibrium we mix a percentage of our nut hands into our smaller size betting range to the point where our opponent is indifferent between his actions against our small bet range (and can't exploit us with raises).
Sort of this is semantics, but I win when he folds here also. I'm never folding so I win this pot 75% of the time. I win much less often when my bet is called.
Same as the previous poster Kevin Sharp, I also think your formula doesn't work correctly with chops. Lets take that typical situation of us 3betting and opponent just calling, with 9TJQx runout, where both of us have lot of kings but only the 3bettor has AK. If our range mostly chops against his range and sometimes win, then our "equity" is actually be pretty low, since big part of it is the 50% equity chop. But if we are only chopping and sometimes winning, then it's pretty obvious we should just go for all-in no matter how much deep, since nothing can go wrong.
Getting called by chop nets us 0 dollars from our bet (Win 50/Lose 50 = 0 EV bet). This means that to make money when we often chop with our opponent, we need to bet smaller. The only money will really win is against weaker hands that our forced to call.
In your example, likely optimal strategy is to bet smaller with Kx and to jam AK with balanced bluffs.
We also win money, if we FOLD out a chop. If we bet large enough, opponent will be forced to start folding kings. Whether our strategy should prefer extracting value from weaker hands or folding out chops with overbets is another thing. Better example would be wheel straight 2345, where only one player reps 6, but aces are very likely for both players. Thats a pretty common spot for overbets which are supposed to fold out chops. And the formula you are using is gonna recommend way too small bet, because it's gonna act as if we are likely to lose often due to much less than 100% equity (even though we can't actually lose). Yet our strategy should be huge overbet with both aces and sixes with the intent of folding out chops.
I'm sure we can contrive some strategy where his entire range is chops and our entire range is chops + nuts that we should now overbet our chops. In general though when ranges include other hands then smaller bets with chops make sense. You can test your hypothesis in Pio. I'm happy to be wrong.
It actually means the formula is not applicable for some reason. It only works within the constraints and 100% equity isn't included within range. With 100% equity, you should always go all-in without range considerations.
Equity = Hero's equity
Bluff Catcher = Villain's hand
I'm using bluff catcher as a hand that beats our bluffs but not the value hand. We know that our opponent folds some % of the time to our bet, so a hand that has 90% equity against the entire range and bets pot will only win 80% of the time against hands that will call the river. We can describe this change as (90% equity - 50% Folding Frequency / (50% Calling Frequency).
Hi,
A few questions :
1. in Tipton's formula, is "Equity" our hand's equity vs Villain's whole range or the equity vs Villain's calling range?
If it's the equity vs Villain's calling range, which seems to be the case (this is what you said in a previous comment), it seems hard / impossible to determine what Villain will call with (so it's hard / impossible to determine our equity vs V's calling range) before determining our betsizing (especially if Villain calls 1-A).
For example, in the 2nd hand with T8o : do you think Villain calls 2.3*pot with AJ? And in the Ac3c hand, do you think Villain will call your River bet with KcJc (which is one of the worst bluffcatching hand blockers wise)?
On the other hand, @0:29:44 you say you set "the hands you think he has on the river" (not the ones you think he calls with), so I am still not sure what is the Villain's range we take into consideration when evaluating the equity?
2. could this formula be used for flop and turn spots?
3. regarding the idea of using this formula with several ranges on the River (let's say 3 ranges : Nuts+bluff, strong+bluff, thinValue+Bluffs) : this sounds great, but I hardly see how this could be done, because to build each one of these 3 ranges, the number of bluffs for any value hand depends on the betsize we use, and in order to use this formula to calculate the betsize, we need to know our equity, which implies that we know what hands are in our range (the more bluffs, the less equity). so calculating the optimal betsizing requires to know the equity, which requires to know the range composition, which implies to know the betsizing... this is endless...
4. Does Tipton suggest any method or any other formula to deal with the bluffing spots and have an overall balanced strategy using this value bet sizing formula?
PS : @0:26:14 + @0:31:25 "and he calls relatively quickly" : is there a feature that saves the timings in HEM? or you just levelled yourself vs your replayer?
Thank you for the questions!
.@ 1. Practical considerations differ from theoretical ones. If my opponent plays badly, then I don't need optimal betsizing. I just need to pick the size which makes him make the biggest mistake.
@ 2. No - It'd need considerable modifications to do deal with future equity considerations (suckouts)
@ 3. It is possible, pio, simplyposftlop, GTORB do this effortlessly. If you know your range and your opponents range. You can determine GTO betsizings and frequencies.
@ 4. I leveled my myself against my replayer :) . Tipton suggests pllaying your range in a manner that maximizes its value and use your bluffs to force our opposition to call our value bets. This formula follows from this exploration.
Hi,
thank you for the answers!
1. Sorry, but I still don't understand if "Equity" should be our hand's equity vs Villain's whole range or the equity vs Villain's calling range?
3. I don't know about simplyposftlop & GTORB, but as far as I know, PioSOLVER doesn't do what we are talking about (or this is a feature I missed?) : when you solve a postflop spot with PioSolver, you set the betsizings before launching the solver, and then PioSolver deduces the optimal ranges for each possible action based on these betsizings. But here, the betsizings are not determined : they are precisely what we look for.
What I meant with this question #3 is that it is possible of course to deduce a betsizing from a range or a range from a betsizing (PioSOLVER does this), but I hardly see how to use this formula with split ranges given that the composition of each range depends on the bluff:value ratio, which depends on the betsizing, which depends on the Equity, which depends on the composition of the range... This is an endless circle.
Or maybe the formula is made so that we only have to take into account the equity of our Value range and then we can build the bluffing range corresponding to this betsizing?
Hi Tyler, please, can you answer my previous questions?
Also, are you sure you retranscripted well Tipton's formula?
I get strange results (with Equity = Hero's hand Equity vs Villain's calling range).
For example, with S2P ratio = 4.33
If Hero's equity = 99.39% -> B* = 4.33pot (which is OK)
But :
If Hero's equity = 98.48% -> B = 21.78pot (which is NOT OK)
If Hero's equity = 97.56% -> B = 7.52pot (which is NOT OK)
If Hero's equity = 96.33% -> B = 4.09*pot (which is OK)
Any idea of what's happening here?
Are you sure that :
Tipton 's S = stack / pot
Tipton 's T = 1-Equity
?
Assumption for the formula to work:
a. You have a good understanding of your opponents range and your own range.
If we know both ranges then we can use PIO (insert multiple betsizes into the solver) to find an optimal strategy with optimal betsizes. The more betsizes we use the closer the solution will be to GTO for NL.
b. If we don't have PIO, use the median hand equity in your value betting range as Tipton optimal betsizing hand. Its an approximation, but it will hold up well against exploitation and will rarely be awful .
@Betsizes -> any betsizes over stack size is considered out of range in Tipton's formula. All the funny numbers are telling you that we should be betting over stack size here (or all-in in human speak).
P.S. I actually get -128 at 99% here, which means we are clearly out of bounds.
Hi,
Actually, I'm very surprised by your answer to question #1 : Equity should be against the whole range
Let's take a black & white example : let's say Villain's range is made of air+slowplayed strong hands (example : Hero opens BTN with 7's and Villain calls in SB (SB range includes poket pairs up to JJ) ; Villain XRaised a polar range (sets+draws) on 3c7dTd and barrel turn 2h and checks River 2h when no draw is completed and also Turn and River cards don't hit Vilain's range, with this final runout : 3c7dTd2h2s). Now BTN thinks about value betting his mid FH.
Don't you think the only equity which matters in this spot is BTN's equity vs Villain's not folding range (vs Villain's calling or raising hands)?
How could the equity versus the folding range impact our betsizing here, given that all these busted draws will fold anyway, whatever the sizing? We are not talking about inducing here I guess.
When I watch your vid, it seems that most of the time, you are calculating your equity vs Villain's calling range, except @0:29:44 which is not clear regarding that question.
Thank you for your answers!
Its pointless to calculate equity against hands that will fold to any betsize and don't beat my bluffs. They aren't in the handrange that we calculate equity against because they are always folds.
We calculate our equity vs villains defending range on the river to derive a optimal bet size however, villains defending range is a function of our bet size, so how can we accurately assign them a bluffcatching range if we dont know our bet size in the first place?
I guess from what I understand then is we are calculating our range vs villains range up to that point in the hand minus any hands in villains range that would not be able to beat our weakest bluff?
secondly regarding adding bluffs,,
I think this makes sense, " maybe the formula is made so that we only have to take into account the equity of our Value range and then we can build the bluffing range corresponding to this betsizing?"
Otherwise if the change in equity vs villains range when adding bluffs is to be considered, when could we stop iterating?
I've read through some of the previous discussions about how betting big will throw our range off balance. I kinda get the point of your responses, but can I sum it up by saying that you made an exploitative adjustment?
I tried to duplicate your Excel form and got the same answers to your examples in the vid. However, when I tried some 'extreme' equity&SPR combos, the results are somewhat strange.
i.e., I tried equity=99%, SPR=2, the optimal bet sizing came up negative. Would you say this is due to the lack of some form of boundary conditions inherited to the equation?
For equity=0.99, SPR=2, it should be an easy shove as the optimal bet sizing is definitely greater than 8xpot. It seems whenever it is an 'obvious' situation, the result would turn out negative.
Great video, Tyler! Interesting how tiny changes in trap combinations can so drastically bring down the optimal bet size from infinity to half-pot or less...
The 67hh hand where you rivered the flush was particularly interesting - I was surprised by how small we bet there, when we are unlikely to be bluffed by anything but the naked Ah. Do you think we could exploitatively bet bigger, especially against imperfect/non-clairvoyant opponents?
This is a bit of rabbit hole. If we can profitably call a raise, that will make our bet more profitable which will increase the optimal betsize.
If they can bluff raise us, our betsize falls as their bluffing frequency goes to GTO. After the bluffing frequency gets bigger than GTO than our profitably will increase again and so will the optimal betsize.
One more thing: Do we have to look at the equity vs their entire range or just vs their calling range?
I just had a spot where I got bet into on the river and I felt like vs their range I had a significant equity advantage whereas vs. their calling range if I raised, I would have very little equity.
"it's an interesting academic spot but i am not sure how effective it will be for poker games" - i think, it should be put as a disclaimer. but got to it only on the last seconds of the video.
it's, in fact, interesting to see that 7% change in equity can give such a drastic difference in optimal bet-sizing. but it's not even optimal (as far as i got it, uses formula that, probably can be improved and also completely relies on opponent's range. and it's not game theory optimal)
sorry, just a bit disappointed that only got to the last phrases at the end of the video. and i think, the whole reasoning part of great influence of change of equity on bet-sizing could have summed up in much less than 30 mins.
maybe you could recommend newer videos that go more into depth about bet sizing?
it would be nice to have some disclaimer or smth. because trying to find optimal strategies on your web-site to apply to my game and yet been failing but haven't explored much, have to say. there's kinda little navigation possible. only learning paths, where u have videos like this that u know, are a bit outdated or not applicable to the game.
i am sorry if i come across as a rude person. i didn't really mean to offend anyone. but i was really kinda expecting more from such a title as "optimal bet sizing strategies"
update: Tyler answered me personally. really appreciated it. thanks.
Loading 106 Comments...
Here is access to the worksheet. If anyone wants to try it themselves.
Optimal Betsizing Excel Document
Tyler, you mentioned Titpon's HU book at start of this video.. just curious if you have learned the majority of how Game Theory applies to poker through books? and if so, which books do you think offer the best information on this?
(I know the following authors have written books on GTO Poker: Will Tipton, Matt Janda, Bill Chen and Jared Ankenman, and Philip Newall.. have you read the books by all of these authors? and are there any other authors that you know of that have made a good contribution to this area? )
The mathematics of poker is the best. The other books are all good. I read them all because even .01 bbs increase pays for the book.
Hey Tyler, great video, very interesting stuff... it seems like the moral of the story is that we need to be careful in the assumptions we make about what hands are still in our opponents range on the river, because small mistakes there could lead to large overbetting mistakes...
That's a great summation! I was surprised at how much the betsizing oscillate on small equity differences. Adding an EV calculation into the excel spreadsheet would be of good value.
Great video. Are there ever any spots where the optimal bet sizing formula might give us a output that is a very large bet size, but our range won't be able to come up with enough bluffs to balance that bet size? In this case are we better off tailoring our bet size down to get the appropriate value:air ratio in or do we just choose the optimal bet size and add all of our air and villain's best response is to just fold 100% of his bluff catchers? It seems like in the latter case we give ourselves a nice free roll vs non-clairvoyant players.
Justification for the smaller betsize is that we could bet smaller with our nut hands, get called gain value, then bet bigger with our bluffs and get folds. So the right play here is for our opponent to fold to any betsize. From a practical standpoint, I'd just go all in, because it makes me seem more aggressive and can never be wrong and is unexploitable. AND its far bigger mistake for them to call the all-in bet with a 1-A strategy, then to call a small bet with 1-A strategy. Let them make big mistakes!
incredible video. In this example, is jamming despite the fact that we dont have sufficient bluffs better than just the size that balances our value to bluff ratio?
Yes, because if our opponent chooses to call, he now loses money (when we bet bigger than size that balances our values to bluff ratio). If we only balance he breaks even, so calling isn't a really a mistake.
so if we have a value hand that wants to bet 75% pot, but we only have enough bluffs to support a 50% pot bet, we should bet 75% of pot regardless? is this because either way, we win the whole pot (bc calling 50% bet has 0 EV and folding to the 75% bet has 0 ev)? so we freeroll that he by mistake might incorrectly call the 75% bet?
And is this the maximum EV for our whole range if its EV is the entire pot on the river? (bc if our EV cud get any higher, our opponent cud just better their expectation by folding their entire range?)
sorry for all the questions but wud really appreciate if u cud comment on this question above ^. Appreciate you taking the time to answer everyone and so promptly. Im just really thinking about this bet sizing strat and I think without adequate bluffs in my range, ive been sizing down for the reason to be 'balanced' when makes no sense to do so.
This is a cool graph. If you bet >= 50% pot in your example then your EV against optimal strategy is always = 1 pot. That optimal strategy is always fold at > 50% pot (and call or fold when bet = 50% pot). However if our opponent plays suboptimally calls any betsize sometime our EV > 1 pot at bet > 50% (and our EV keeps increasing as we bet bigger) and EV = 1 pot when bet = 50%. So we are really freerolling our opposition by betting 75% pot here. Either we win 1 pot against GTO or we win > 1 pot against Anti-GTO.
perfect thank you
32:00
45o hand you lead A23r flop BTN v BB. I don't think I play a leading range on this texture from the BB as I just have a pretty sizable range disadvantage and only a slight nut advantage having all 45 combos where btn likely only has 45s. What's the idea behind that lead and why you do prefer a lead to x/ca or x/r?
I thought this opponent was tight enough to only have suited fours, whereas I felt I was playing K4o, Q4o, 64o and 54o in this spot. Given board texture, my range has a real advantage on the 5 and he checks close to 100% of the time in position. This makes betting very appealing (its also usually bet as a bluff because he will rarely call the turn and river here with AJ and that's close to the cutoff for a profitable bluff. ).
Yeah, I think the turn lead is good but iirc you chose to donk bet flop as well. I think in real time you misread the flop action.
You are right I did misread flop action and yes its bad to bet the flop. It was a mistake :(
Surprised to see that 10% equity can have such a drastic effect on bet size.
Its pretty incredible what small perturbations to the system can do :). Shows just how essential good hand reading is (and tricking your opponent into misreading your own hand).
I think it makes more intuitive sense if you think of betsize as being more related to 1-(equity) when equity gets closer to 1
Great video, really motivated me to put some focussed work into my strategy.
Thanks flux!
Hey Tyler,
nitpicky question because I might be misunderstanding something.
The Trap equation is written as:
((1 - Equity) - Fold Frequency)/(Calling Frequency) = Traps
Shouldn't this be:
1 - ((Equity - Fold Frequency)/(Calling Frequency))= Traps ?
Really interesting video!
You're right Paul. Good Catch!
good old PEMDAS
Not exactly the topic of the video but a spot I'm interested in:
16:40 6cTh3dAd "the ace hits his range a lot harder than mine and slowplaying my traps here is really important"
I don't really believe in this (slowplaying the traps in this spot). This particular hand could be a good candidate to check call, but I wouldn't totally consider it a trap anyways, which I guess we see in the equity sim (and we will want to have some pretty good 2 street check calling hands here).
I prefer an overbet strategy with the nut hands (33,66, AT for sure) at a high frequency instead of a check raise. If he's stabbing or bet calling the turn too often, then we can start employing a higher c/r freq as an adjustment.
In theory I believe the overbet strategy should yield more EV than a check raise in a spot where we have significant nut combos and our opponent basically never has nut combos (traditional polar vs capped concepts etc). This could tie back into the topic of the video, where 33 has extremely high equity and we can overbet the turn and then overbet many rivers for a huge sizing as an optimal strategy.
Of course in the optimal solution there is probably some degree of mixed strategy where we do check percentages of those nut combos at equilibrium, but I don't think it has to be very often.
I like your logic and I'd like this post twice if I could!
I should qualify my thought with check a3 and a6 here to strengthen my range, but also be willing to overbet hands clearly over the top of his range (AT, 66, 33).
i agree with this analysis but a few things: 1. TT seems to be a very reasonable check back ( i do it a lot as a defense versus ur strat and the fact that standardly vbetting 3 streets wont work well with blocker effects) 2. AA can check at a certain frequency as well on flop.
So when we start blasting in overbets, we start to run into these combos on occasion when we have 33/66 (not so much with AT bc of blockers obv), but i doubt this is a huge concern.
I do agree though an overbet leading strategy can work well, and balance it with the lots of straight draws/FDs we will have without SD value that want to realize their equity.
We arent leading any other hands though right? I think an overbet lead or a check is best.
We arent leading any other hands though right? I think an overbet lead or a check is best.
Agreed. We almost always want to be check calling top pair here, so we have very little incentive to construct a normal size leading range.
The EV of check raising don't come from the fact that he will not always cbetting his air hands on the flop and can delay bet them at a certain frequency turn as this card hits his range pretty well ? We can put pressure on his As x by check raising large and overbet river and include the appropriate ratio of bluffs. I wouldn't bet too too much because as you said he can have some traps (TT/AA sometimes), and if he knows our strategy it incentives him to check back a lot of other trap hands
If it goes check check we can always bet large on the river, not too large imo as he can easily check back his weakest As x turn and bluff catch river no ? I would probably bet pot or small overbet and include some bluffs.
I"m curious why Garrett and FBB both like over betting turn compared to x/r'ing. It looks like a turn where we're going to face a bet from a wider range than we're going to get a call from when we bet, so wouldn't our value region be gaining the most from check/raising? I would think Ax+air will make up more than Ax, Tx-3x but I could be miscounting there. I guess I should also add that we likely make more vs his Ax by taking the x/r line rather than over bet turn, bet river.
I've played around with the formula in the spreadsheet a bit, and one thing I noticed is that increasing stack size makes the optimal bet size decrease. Is this because villain's traps are assumed 100% equity and he can just shove vs our bet and add the appropriate number of bluffs to make us indifferent? Apologies in advance if the question is nonsensical as much of this material is over my head. Thanks for another great video.
Yes, exactly, Caesar, it assumes villain is clairovoyant and will always shove any hand better + indifferent bluffs over our bet.
Tyler, optimal bet sizing is definitely an interesting topic, but how reliable do you think what you found out is to the games you play which probably aren't this optimal with sizing. Does all what you've discovered by doing math make you want to bet closer to the optimal bet sizing or is that just something you did out of interest and curiosity?
The key issue is the small perturbations in the system causing large swings in betsizing, so the numbers themselves will never be terribly valuable. What is valuable is realizing that betting 1/3rd pot with a nut hand is or overbetting a "range merge" value hand is a big mistake the vast majority of the time. I think about this video as more of a lesson in how NOT to bet.
Hi Tyler,
I enjoyed the video. For the most part, I feel like I understand the general principle of Tipton's formula but am having trouble reconciling it with betsizing strategies I've used or seen in the past.
In the video, you use the equity of your specific hand v opponent's range in the formula. However, in game, I assume you are not usually scaling your betsizes according to the equity of your specific hand. In practice, does it make sense use the [equity of our entire value range] to estimate a single bet size for our entire value and bluffing range?
Thanks!
I also wanted to point this out with a couple more thoughts to the question.
Since we can't valuebet every single hand with its optimal betsizing against a good opponent we group our value hands in different betting ranges.
Consider this example: we decide to have two betsizes in a river spot where a straight is possible. In the smaller betsizing we can have some 2pair and sets and a small % of straights + bluffs. In the bigger one we have only nut hands+bluffs. So when we bet for the smaller betsizing should we:
a) bet a size that is 100% accurate to the weakest hand we valuebet;
b) bet a size that is not optimal for any of our value hands but is somewhat inbetween.
If option b) is the right answer then it becomes really tough to calculate which betsize we should use for our range. In many spots if we do an in-between size we might risk of going over the valuebetting threshold for our weakest hand, resulting in a bad bet with our weakest value and lower than optimal with our better value hands that comprise that range. It seems to me there's room to possibly expand Tipton's formula to include these considerations to explore optimal range betsizing.
Cloud nailed the answer.
Great video, Tyler!
Great video, Tyler! Thank you for the files.
19:00 you divided your stack by the pot, but villain has shorter stack(1.76 pot), so the optimal bet size is 2/3.
Good Catch Seth!
Interesting concept, really like the video!
But shouldnt we use range vs range equity instead of hand vs range equity for our calculations? I dont really understand how we could apply this line of logic for our bluffing sizes if we just use the equity for single hands.
Using one or two betsizes for entire ranges makes a lot of sense, but its more demonstrative to show a hand vs range situation. However, you can easily extend the logic to range betsizes.
great video.
If we do not have enough bluffs to balance our sizing, and our opponent is clairvoyant, should we go with a smaller sizing that he is indifferent to calling to?
You say above we learn that we should not bet small with our nut hands, but if that is the only way we can get called, than isn't that correct?
Thanks FBB, Go bigger, because we always win > pot. (If he correctly folds, we win pot). If he calls incorrectly, we win > pot.
And yes there is some strategy choice against a bad player, where going allin with bluffs and betting small with value bets is the best play. But I have rarely met this sort of player and if he starts foldign to small bets and calling big ones we now lose money in this situation. Seems like a big mistake to take a spot where we win > pot and turn into a -EV situation on the off chance our opponent meets some weak tight specifications.
Very helpful video. The video also portrays the limitations of the human mind when playing a live game. In theory, you’re exploitable if your choose a bet size that is far away from the optimal bet size. Understanding that the human mind can’t calculate this quick enough, is there a realistic strategy to minimize exploitability with regard to bet size? It was pretty eye opening how minor changes to equity could have such an effect on bet size. I guess something similar to Zach Freeman’s recent video (Building Realistic Strategies For Strong Ranges On Poor Flops) but in slightly different context…
Every movement toward GTO betsize will yield improvements in EV. I like to think about more as evolution rather than multiplication. In evolution, every animal slowly adapts better to its environment (moves close to GTO). But in multiplication 7 X 7 = 49 is always true and if I wrote 7 X 7 = 51 it would be wrong (Its either right or wrong).
I wonder how these concepts can be effectively utilized in live play?
Hand read well and understand your own range. I know this sounds fatuous, but these really are the prerequisites to application.
Doesn't it make a difference in the last hand, that all the equity that he has comes from chops, and you're actually beat ~0% of the time (and thus cannot value cut yourself)?? Seems misleading that you would use the same numbers on the spreadsheet as if you were beat ~9% of the time. I don't think the EV would be much lower if you just shoved there, which is obv what you will be wanting to do with 64.
Though maybe it's optimal to shove 64 and air, and vbet 54 smaller.
Actually the equity number accounts for chops (it adds 50% equity hands into the range for all chops). We don't want to end up in situation where we are only called by 4x and 64s. Then our bet actually becomes negative -- chop with 4x and lose to 64s.
youre killing it! great vid
Im trying to reconcile 2 modes of thought when i reach these river spots. My current one is "ok, i have x amount of value bets, which allows me to have x amount of bluffs," and i then pick a sizing.
In this video you are offering another mode/layer of thought: "how much equity does this specific hand have against his range, and whats my optimal bet size given stacks?" My question is how you go about bringing these two together.
Its a good question, and ultimately the answer is that the average range equity wins out. If there is not enough bluffs in your hand range, you will take a hand with showdwon value and turn it into a bluff (at an optimal sizing for your hand range. (Hand equity was for example only). This means all your bluffs will be +EV and your showdown value hand will be equal EV between checking and betting. Its actually a super awesome spot to be in. :)
aren't your bluffs zero EV in a balanced range? if we dont have enough bluffs, we take worse hands in range (probably thats wins lets say 5% of time) and bluff them but how do they stay at +5% of pot in EV? It still loses to all their bluff catchers. So you expect ppl to slightly overfold to keep it at around +5% of pot EV?
Hi FBB,
If we bet twice pot and don't have enough bluffs in our range, then our opponent should always fold. Our bluffs are now worth more than zero. They are worth 1 pot. So we should always bet our bluffs, because checking them is worth zero EV and betting is +EV. If we continue with a large range with some showdown value hand, we should add bluffing with hands that have less than 1 pot EV in this example, because when our opponent folds we make 1 pot EV. Eventuallly our opponent will settle on a range that makes the strongest "bluff" (hand with showdown value) indifferent to calling. All bluffs lower than this will be positive. I'd encourage you to construct some ranges in a free version of piosolver and try this out. Seeing is believing.
"eventually our opponent will settle on a range that makes the strongest "bluff" indifferent to calling." Can you expand or elaborate this point? Im not sure I understand, and i feel its the crux of your point.
Otherwise we wouldn't bluff enough because our bluffing range of 0 EV bluffs ( betting are strongest bluff would be negative so we would check ti) this would be less than enough to make him indifferent to calling so he would always fold. Which means we would gain vaue against by bettig our strongest bluff. This oscillation is indicative of exploitative play.
Nice Vid.
Why does the formula return negative values for an EQ of 0,55 and SPR 1 . Aren't we supposed to bet IP in that case?
oops my bad... after checking some numbers.. if there is money behind, villain raises his nuts along some bluffs denying our share of the pot making it inferior to x/back and showdown our hand.
(10:30) What is the name of the name of that Equity Calculator you use?
Holdeq it's a crev addon
What are your thoughts on Snowie's Preflop Advisor for 100bb starting stacks?
Solid - I think its a good starting point for a beginning strategy. It doesn't do anything obviously preposterous.
Hey Tyler!
First of all great video, you're awesome!
My question is when we use this formula should we compare against villan's full range he gets to the river with or against the bluffcatching range? @18:25 with the A3 two pair hand you put Ax and KdQd, KdJd, with I don't think villain will bet/call turn and then call river, but in the other example with A5 3b pot you said he won't bluffcatch with hands like QJ and put only bluffcatching hands in his range, but this changes our equity drastically and as we saw that matters a LOT.
P.S.: Tyler is not only a really entertaining/smart person to learn from, but he makes great drinking-game videos as well. When you hear 'in this situation' just take a shot with your friends. :)
Hi Niz,
Thanks for the compliments! We should compare against his bluffing catching. In the first spot with A3 both KqQd and KdJd are bluffcatching hands. Most of my bluffs will be low flush draws/gutshots so those hands actually have decent equity against my range. In the A5 hand of course we have 87hh, JhTh, QhTh+ but those are only 4 combos, so QJ only has 10% against my range (which makes it an autofold).
Might be good to do a video on preflop range construction!
There are a lot of questions in here about how the formula applies to playing our range, which I am interested in as well. Perhaps it could be helpful to think of this formula as a way to find the optimal bet size for each hand in a vacuum, prior to constructing our overall strategy.
As I understand it, this is a formula for bet sizing pre-equilibration. In our actual strategy, we will mix hands into different ranges to keep our opponent indifferent between his actions against each range.
For example, this formula shows us that our nut hands want to bet very big and our thinner value hands want to bet smaller based on their equity. But if we always bet big with the nuts and smaller with our thin VB's, then our opponent can attack our smaller bet size. So at equilibrium we mix a percentage of our nut hands into our smaller size betting range to the point where our opponent is indifferent between his actions against our small bet range (and can't exploit us with raises).
I appreciate your thoughts. Well said!
12:30 - "And I win about 3/4 of the time here"
Wouldn't this only be true if he was calling 100% of his range on the river?
Sort of this is semantics, but I win when he folds here also. I'm never folding so I win this pot 75% of the time. I win much less often when my bet is called.
great video, really enjoyed the concept. hope u can do more of these in the future. thank you
Same as the previous poster Kevin Sharp, I also think your formula doesn't work correctly with chops. Lets take that typical situation of us 3betting and opponent just calling, with 9TJQx runout, where both of us have lot of kings but only the 3bettor has AK. If our range mostly chops against his range and sometimes win, then our "equity" is actually be pretty low, since big part of it is the 50% equity chop. But if we are only chopping and sometimes winning, then it's pretty obvious we should just go for all-in no matter how much deep, since nothing can go wrong.
Hi Like,
Getting called by chop nets us 0 dollars from our bet (Win 50/Lose 50 = 0 EV bet). This means that to make money when we often chop with our opponent, we need to bet smaller. The only money will really win is against weaker hands that our forced to call.
In your example, likely optimal strategy is to bet smaller with Kx and to jam AK with balanced bluffs.
We also win money, if we FOLD out a chop. If we bet large enough, opponent will be forced to start folding kings. Whether our strategy should prefer extracting value from weaker hands or folding out chops with overbets is another thing. Better example would be wheel straight 2345, where only one player reps 6, but aces are very likely for both players. Thats a pretty common spot for overbets which are supposed to fold out chops. And the formula you are using is gonna recommend way too small bet, because it's gonna act as if we are likely to lose often due to much less than 100% equity (even though we can't actually lose). Yet our strategy should be huge overbet with both aces and sixes with the intent of folding out chops.
I'm sure we can contrive some strategy where his entire range is chops and our entire range is chops + nuts that we should now overbet our chops. In general though when ranges include other hands then smaller bets with chops make sense. You can test your hypothesis in Pio. I'm happy to be wrong.
one question Tyler. I did come in one of my spots that we have 100% equity, and it gives me -4 something. This means we should always check?
It actually means the formula is not applicable for some reason. It only works within the constraints and 100% equity isn't included within range. With 100% equity, you should always go all-in without range considerations.
Ty sir! one more questions we should allways consider the eff stack size right? not our actual stack size right?
Yes exactly. Think of it like a 20bb cap game where we have 4000 bbs behind. We'll only calculate the math based on that 40bb pot.
You are scaring me,
Thank goodness for Tiptons formula ;D
TY again you make excellent videos!!!
why (equity - folding frequency)/calling frequency = bluff catcher?
im one of ur fans now! haha
Equity = Hero's equity
Bluff Catcher = Villain's hand
I'm using bluff catcher as a hand that beats our bluffs but not the value hand. We know that our opponent folds some % of the time to our bet, so a hand that has 90% equity against the entire range and bets pot will only win 80% of the time against hands that will call the river. We can describe this change as (90% equity - 50% Folding Frequency / (50% Calling Frequency).
Hi,
A few questions :
1. in Tipton's formula, is "Equity" our hand's equity vs Villain's whole range or the equity vs Villain's calling range?
If it's the equity vs Villain's calling range, which seems to be the case (this is what you said in a previous comment), it seems hard / impossible to determine what Villain will call with (so it's hard / impossible to determine our equity vs V's calling range) before determining our betsizing (especially if Villain calls 1-A).
For example, in the 2nd hand with T8o : do you think Villain calls 2.3*pot with AJ? And in the Ac3c hand, do you think Villain will call your River bet with KcJc (which is one of the worst bluffcatching hand blockers wise)?
On the other hand, @0:29:44 you say you set "the hands you think he has on the river" (not the ones you think he calls with), so I am still not sure what is the Villain's range we take into consideration when evaluating the equity?
2. could this formula be used for flop and turn spots?
3. regarding the idea of using this formula with several ranges on the River (let's say 3 ranges : Nuts+bluff, strong+bluff, thinValue+Bluffs) : this sounds great, but I hardly see how this could be done, because to build each one of these 3 ranges, the number of bluffs for any value hand depends on the betsize we use, and in order to use this formula to calculate the betsize, we need to know our equity, which implies that we know what hands are in our range (the more bluffs, the less equity). so calculating the optimal betsizing requires to know the equity, which requires to know the range composition, which implies to know the betsizing... this is endless...
4. Does Tipton suggest any method or any other formula to deal with the bluffing spots and have an overall balanced strategy using this value bet sizing formula?
PS : @0:26:14 + @0:31:25 "and he calls relatively quickly" : is there a feature that saves the timings in HEM? or you just levelled yourself vs your replayer?
Thank you for the questions!
.@ 1. Practical considerations differ from theoretical ones. If my opponent plays badly, then I don't need optimal betsizing. I just need to pick the size which makes him make the biggest mistake.
@ 2. No - It'd need considerable modifications to do deal with future equity considerations (suckouts)
@ 3. It is possible, pio, simplyposftlop, GTORB do this effortlessly. If you know your range and your opponents range. You can determine GTO betsizings and frequencies.
@ 4. I leveled my myself against my replayer :) . Tipton suggests pllaying your range in a manner that maximizes its value and use your bluffs to force our opposition to call our value bets. This formula follows from this exploration.
Hi,
thank you for the answers!
1. Sorry, but I still don't understand if "Equity" should be our hand's equity vs Villain's whole range or the equity vs Villain's calling range?
3. I don't know about simplyposftlop & GTORB, but as far as I know, PioSOLVER doesn't do what we are talking about (or this is a feature I missed?) : when you solve a postflop spot with PioSolver, you set the betsizings before launching the solver, and then PioSolver deduces the optimal ranges for each possible action based on these betsizings. But here, the betsizings are not determined : they are precisely what we look for.
What I meant with this question #3 is that it is possible of course to deduce a betsizing from a range or a range from a betsizing (PioSOLVER does this), but I hardly see how to use this formula with split ranges given that the composition of each range depends on the bluff:value ratio, which depends on the betsizing, which depends on the Equity, which depends on the composition of the range... This is an endless circle.
Or maybe the formula is made so that we only have to take into account the equity of our Value range and then we can build the bluffing range corresponding to this betsizing?
Hi Tyler, please, can you answer my previous questions?
Also, are you sure you retranscripted well Tipton's formula?
I get strange results (with Equity = Hero's hand Equity vs Villain's calling range).
For example, with S2P ratio = 4.33
If Hero's equity = 99.39% -> B* = 4.33pot (which is OK)
But :
If Hero's equity = 98.48% -> B = 21.78pot (which is NOT OK)
If Hero's equity = 97.56% -> B = 7.52pot (which is NOT OK)
If Hero's equity = 96.33% -> B = 4.09*pot (which is OK)
Any idea of what's happening here?
Are you sure that :
Tipton 's S = stack / pot
Tipton 's T = 1-Equity
?
thanks
a. You have a good understanding of your opponents range and your own range.
If we know both ranges then we can use PIO (insert multiple betsizes into the solver) to find an optimal strategy with optimal betsizes. The more betsizes we use the closer the solution will be to GTO for NL.
b. If we don't have PIO, use the median hand equity in your value betting range as Tipton optimal betsizing hand. Its an approximation, but it will hold up well against exploitation and will rarely be awful .
@Betsizes -> any betsizes over stack size is considered out of range in Tipton's formula. All the funny numbers are telling you that we should be betting over stack size here (or all-in in human speak).
P.S. I actually get -128 at 99% here, which means we are clearly out of bounds.
Just a sanity test, getting -128 would infer a shove correct? I thought when optimal bet size was negative it inferred checking > betting?
Yes, it's shove.
Hi,
Actually, I'm very surprised by your answer to question #1 :
Equity should be against the whole range
Let's take a black & white example : let's say Villain's range is made of air+slowplayed strong hands (example : Hero opens BTN with 7's and Villain calls in SB (SB range includes poket pairs up to JJ) ; Villain XRaised a polar range (sets+draws) on 3c7dTd and barrel turn 2h and checks River 2h when no draw is completed and also Turn and River cards don't hit Vilain's range, with this final runout : 3c7dTd2h2s). Now BTN thinks about value betting his mid FH.
Don't you think the only equity which matters in this spot is BTN's equity vs Villain's not folding range (vs Villain's calling or raising hands)?
How could the equity versus the folding range impact our betsizing here, given that all these busted draws will fold anyway, whatever the sizing? We are not talking about inducing here I guess.
When I watch your vid, it seems that most of the time, you are calculating your equity vs Villain's calling range, except @0:29:44 which is not clear regarding that question.
Thank you for your answers!
Sorry for the confusion.
So Im still confused on the topic.
We calculate our equity vs villains defending range on the river to derive a optimal bet size however, villains defending range is a function of our bet size, so how can we accurately assign them a bluffcatching range if we dont know our bet size in the first place?
I guess from what I understand then is we are calculating our range vs villains range up to that point in the hand minus any hands in villains range that would not be able to beat our weakest bluff?
secondly regarding adding bluffs,,
I think this makes sense, " maybe the formula is made so that we only have to take into account the equity of our Value range and then we can build the bluffing range corresponding to this betsizing?"
Otherwise if the change in equity vs villains range when adding bluffs is to be considered, when could we stop iterating?
Great video as always, Tyler.
I've read through some of the previous discussions about how betting big will throw our range off balance. I kinda get the point of your responses, but can I sum it up by saying that you made an exploitative adjustment?
Cheers
Thanks Bubu!
Yes you could definitely sum this up as an exploitative adjustment :)
Thanks for your response, Tyler!
I tried to duplicate your Excel form and got the same answers to your examples in the vid. However, when I tried some 'extreme' equity&SPR combos, the results are somewhat strange.
i.e., I tried equity=99%, SPR=2, the optimal bet sizing came up negative. Would you say this is due to the lack of some form of boundary conditions inherited to the equation?
Cheers
For equity=0.99, SPR=2, it should be an easy shove as the optimal bet sizing is definitely greater than 8xpot. It seems whenever it is an 'obvious' situation, the result would turn out negative.
Look at 2nd-to-last comment just above your first post.
Cheers!
Cool. Thanks Tyler
Great video, Tyler! Interesting how tiny changes in trap combinations can so drastically bring down the optimal bet size from infinity to half-pot or less...
The 67hh hand where you rivered the flush was particularly interesting - I was surprised by how small we bet there, when we are unlikely to be bluffed by anything but the naked Ah. Do you think we could exploitatively bet bigger, especially against imperfect/non-clairvoyant opponents?
Great vid Tyler.
How do you think would things change if it would be accounted for the fact that we not always lose vs raises, or they can bluff raise us, etc etc.?
This is a bit of rabbit hole. If we can profitably call a raise, that will make our bet more profitable which will increase the optimal betsize.
If they can bluff raise us, our betsize falls as their bluffing frequency goes to GTO. After the bluffing frequency gets bigger than GTO than our profitably will increase again and so will the optimal betsize.
One more thing: Do we have to look at the equity vs their entire range or just vs their calling range?
I just had a spot where I got bet into on the river and I felt like vs their range I had a significant equity advantage whereas vs. their calling range if I raised, I would have very little equity.
Any hand better than your bluffs. If they fold too often, then we aren't playing optimal anymore, so you'll want to choose a different approach.
"it's an interesting academic spot but i am not sure how effective it will be for poker games" - i think, it should be put as a disclaimer. but got to it only on the last seconds of the video.
it's, in fact, interesting to see that 7% change in equity can give such a drastic difference in optimal bet-sizing. but it's not even optimal (as far as i got it, uses formula that, probably can be improved and also completely relies on opponent's range. and it's not game theory optimal)
sorry, just a bit disappointed that only got to the last phrases at the end of the video. and i think, the whole reasoning part of great influence of change of equity on bet-sizing could have summed up in much less than 30 mins.
maybe you could recommend newer videos that go more into depth about bet sizing?
it would be nice to have some disclaimer or smth. because trying to find optimal strategies on your web-site to apply to my game and yet been failing but haven't explored much, have to say. there's kinda little navigation possible. only learning paths, where u have videos like this that u know, are a bit outdated or not applicable to the game.
i am sorry if i come across as a rude person. i didn't really mean to offend anyone. but i was really kinda expecting more from such a title as "optimal bet sizing strategies"
update: Tyler answered me personally. really appreciated it. thanks.
great video tyler thanks!
Thanks Truepower!
Be the first to add a comment
You must upgrade your account to leave a comment.